This article identifies the emergence of the institution-based view as a third leading perspective in strategic management (the first two being the industry-based and resource-based views). We (a) review the roots of the institution-based view, (b) articulate its two core propositions, and (c) outline how this view contributes to the four fundamental questions in strategy. Overall, we suggest that the institution-based view represents the third leg of a strategy tripod, overcomes the long-standing criticisms of the industrybased and resource-based views ' lack of attention to contexts, and contributes significant new insights as part of the broader intellectual movement centered on new institutionalism.
Figures - uploaded by Sunny Li Sun
Author content
All figure content in this area was uploaded by Sunny Li Sun
Content may be subject to copyright.
Discover the world's research
- 20+ million members
- 135+ million publications
- 700k+ research projects
Join for free
ARTICLE
The Institution-Based View as a Third Leg for a
Strategy Tripod
by Mike W. Peng, Sunny Li Sun, Brian Pinkham, and Hao Chen
Executive Overview
This article identifies the emergence of the institution-based view as a third leading perspective in strategic
management (the first two being the industry-based and resource-based views). We (a) review the roots of
the institution-based view, (b) articulate its two core propositions, and (c) outline how this view
contributes to the four fundamental questions in strategy. Overall, we suggest that the institution-based
view represents the third leg of a strategy tripod, overcomes the long-standing criticisms of the industry-
based and resource-based views' lack of attention to contexts, and contributes significant new insights as
part of the broader intellectual movement centered on new institutionalism.
A
s part of a broader intellectual movement cen-
tered on new institutionalism throughout the
social sciences in recent decades (DiMaggio &
Powell, 1983, 1991; North, 1990, 2005; Scott,
1987, 1995, 2008b; Williamson, 1975, 1985), stra-
tegic management researchers have increasingly
realized that institutions are more than back-
ground conditions (Oliver, 1997; Peng & Heath,
1996). Instead, "institutions directly determine
what arrows a firm has in its quiver as it struggles to
formulate and implement strategy" (Ingram & Sil-
verman, 2002, p. 20, emphasis added). Conse-
quently, an institution-based view of strategic man-
agement has emerged (Peng, 2002, 2003). More
important, this view has been argued to be one of
the three leading perspectives in strategic manage-
ment—the other two being the industry-based and
resource-based views (Peng, 2006, 2009).
With an age of approximately 30 years, strate-
gic management ("strategy" in short) is a rela-
tively young discipline that is constantly in search
of new perspectives (Hambrick & Chen, 2008).
Its first period of growth was in the 1980s, when
Porter (1980) introduced what we now call the
industry-based view. The second period of growth
took off in the 1990s, propelled by the resource-
based view advocated by Barney (1991). We argue
that the third period of growth, largely in the last
decade or so, has been underpinned by the rise of
the institution-based view. Since it takes three
legs to sustain a platform, we believe that the
institution-based view has significantly enriched
the strategy discipline by adding a third leg, lead-
ing to a strategy tripod shown in Figure 1.
What are the origins of the institution-based
We thank the AMP editor, Garry Bruton, and two anonymous review-
ers for excellent guidance and encouragement, Dick Scott for helpful
written comments, and Joseph Clougherty and Klaus Meyer for interesting
discussion. This research was supported in part by a National Science
Foundation CAREER Grant (SES 0552089). All views and errors are ours
and are not those of the NSF.
Mike W. Peng (mikepeng@utdallas.edu) is the Provost's Distinguished Professor of Global Strategy at the University of Texas at Dallas and
Editor-in-Chief of the Asia Pacific Journal of Management.
Sunny Li Sun (lxs055000@utdallas.edu) is a doctoral candidate at the University of Texas at Dallas.
Brian Pinkham (brian.pinkham@utdallas.edu) is a doctoral student at the University of Texas at Dallas.
Hao Chen (chloechenhao@utdallas.edu) is a doctoral student at the University of Texas at Dallas.
2009 63Peng, Sun, Pinkham, and Chen
Copyright by the Academy of Management; all rights reserved. Contents may not be copied, e-mailed, posted to a listserv, or otherwise transmitted without the copyright holder's express written
permission. Users may print, download, or e-mail articles for individual use only.
view in strategy? How does the institution-based
view add to our understanding of strategy above and
beyond what we already know based on the industry-
based and resource-based views? This article ad-
dresses these crucial questions by (a) reviewing the
roots of the institution-based view, (b) articulating
its two core propositions, and (c) outlining how the
institution-based view contributes to the four funda-
mental questions in strategy. While this article draws
on a series of earlier work, its most recent and most
direct companion paper is Peng, Wang, and Jiang
(2008), which emphasized the institution-based
view in international business strategy with a focus
on emerging economies. Differentiating from Peng
et al. (2008), the current article is positioned to
directly speak to the core literature in strategic man-
agement and does not deliberately emphasize the
international aspects. While we discuss research on
emerging economies, we also point out the equally
important ramifications of the institution-based
view for research on developed economies. Combin-
ing the articulation of the two core propositions and
the efforts to address the four fundamental questions
will be the first-time contribution this article makes
to enrich the strategic management literature.
The Roots of the Institution-Based View in
Strategy
T
wo sets of forces underpin the rise of the insti-
tution-based view in strategy: external and in-
ternal. The first is the broader new institution-
alism movement throughout the social sciences in
the last three decades pioneered by economists
(North, 1990; Williamson, 1975, 1985) and soci-
ologists (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983; Meyer &
Rowan, 1977; Scott, 1987, 1995, 2008b). Institu-
tions are commonly known as the "rules of the
game." More formally, institutions are defined by
economist Douglass North (1990, p. 3) as "the
humanly devised constraints that structure human
interaction," and by sociologist W. Richard Scott
(1995, p. 33) as "regulative, normative, and cog-
nitive structures and activities that provide stabil-
ity and meaning to social behavior." While terms
and labels differ on the surface, North's (1990)
scheme of broadly dividing institutions into for-
mal and informal camps is complementary to
Scott's (1995) idea of three supportive pillars:
regulative, normative, and cognitive (see Table
1). Following Peng (2006, 2009), this article will
use an integrative approach, drawing on the best
insights from both economics and sociology as
well as other allied disciplines, instead of sticking
Figure 1
The Institution-Based View: A Third Leg of the Strategy Tripod
Institutional conditions
and transitions
Strategy Performance
Firm-specific resources
and capabilities
Industry-based
competition
Source: Peng (2009, p. 15).
Table 1
Dimensions of Institutions
Degree of Formality
(North, 1990) Examples
Supportive Pillars
(Scott, 1995)
Formal institutions ● Laws ● Regulative (coercive)
● Regulations
● Rules
Informal institutions ● Norms ● Normative
● Cultures ● Cognitive
● Ethics
64 AugustAcademy of Management Perspectives
with terms and labels from one side of the litera-
ture.
Regardless of disciplinary roots, there is a re-
markable consensus on a core proposition: Insti-
tutions matter. As a next step, scholars must
"tackle the harder and more interesting issues of
how they matter, under what circumstances, to
what extent, and in what ways" (Powell, 1996, p.
297). It is this quest to enhance our understanding
of how institutions matter that leads to the prolif-
eration of new institutionalism research through-
out the social sciences, which now includes stra-
tegic management.
In addition to external forces that spill over to
strategy, the institution-based view has also grown
in response to the internal forces within strategy—
specifically, the long-standing criticisms of the
industry-based and resource-based views' lack of
attention to contexts. The industry-based view,
derived largely from the patterns of competition
in the United States in the 1970s (and before),
has been criticized for ignoring histories and in-
stitutions (Narayanan & Fahey, 2005). Take the
very first of Porter's five forces, interfirm rivalry,
and its prescription for a cost leadership strategy.
The industry-based view seldom questions what is
behind such rivalry. In truth, formal government
policies and informal media and consumer senti-
ments regarding the "dos and don'ts" play a sig-
nificant role in shaping competition (Dobbin &
Dowd, 1997; Fligstein, 1990). Under certain in-
stitutional conditions, a cost leadership strategy
can be accused of being unethical—think of the
trouble Wal-Mart faced by pursuing the "everyday
low price" strategy. Under other conditions, a cost
leadership strategy may become illegal—in the Jap-
anese bookselling industry, price fixing is legal
while price competition is banned (Stevenson,
2009). In international trade, the single-minded
pursuit of a cost leadership strategy that ignores
host country trade laws and regulations can easily
attract legal action centered on antidumping
(Schuler, Rehbein, & Cramer, 2002). In short,
the industry-based view has not paid adequate
attention to contexts.
Likewise, the resource-based view has been
criticized for its "little effort to establish appropri-
ate contexts" (Priem & Butler, 2001, p. 32). Valu-
able, rare, and hard-to-imitate resources and ca-
pabilities in one context may become
nonvaluable, plentiful, and easy to imitate in
other contexts (Brouthers, Brouthers, & Werner,
2008; Oliver, 1997). Barney (2001, p. 52) himself
acknowledged the validity of this criticism, noting
that "the value of a firm's resources must be un-
derstood in the specific market context within
which a firm is operating. . . . [T]oo many authors
have simply assumed away this question, and,
thus, have failed to help develop a more complete
theory of firm advantages."
1
For example, Dell's
capabilities in "flexible manufacturing" of PCs
added value when competition was moderately
dynamic. However, in the new context of high-
velocity, dynamic competition, Dell's "flexible
manufacturing" capabilities turned out to be not
flexible enough. Dell ended up approaching con-
tract computer manufacturers with offers to sell
most—and possibly all— of its PC factories (Wall
Street Journal, 2008a).
In summary, externally, the rise of new institu-
tionalism throughout the social sciences has en-
ergized scholarly attention in strategy to focus on
how institutions matter. Internally, the frustration
associated with the industry-based and resource-
based views' lack of adequate attention to con-
texts has called for new theoretical perspectives
that can overcome these drawbacks. The result is
the emergence of the institution-based view
(Peng, 2002, 2006; Peng et al., 2008).
Developing the Third Leg of Strategy
T
o be sure, the influence of the "environment"
(Lawrence & Lorsch, 1969) has long been fea-
tured in the literature. However, strategy re-
search has typically favored a "task environment"
view, which focuses primarily on economic vari-
ables such as market demand and technological
change (Dess & Beard, 1984). Until about the
mid-1990s, researchers rarely looked beyond the
task environment to explore the interactions
1
Barney (2001) was a response to the critique of the resource-based
view made by Priem and Butler (2001). Overall, Barney (2001, p. 52)
argued that Priem and Butler's primary criticisms were "unfounded." Con-
sequently, Barney's acknowledgment of the validity of this specific criticism
on context speaks volumes about this point.
2009 65Peng, Sun, Pinkham, and Chen
among institutions, organizations, and strategic
choices (as critiqued by Narayanan & Fahey,
2005). Instead, a market-based institutional
framework has been taken for granted, and formal
institutions (such as laws and regulations) and
informal institutions (such as cultures and norms)
have been assumed away as "background." While
some argue that this treatment of institutions as
background conditions is insufficient to gain a
deeper understanding of strategic behavior in de-
veloped economies (Clougherty, 2005; Oliver &
Holzinger, 2008; Scott, 2008b), its deficiency be-
comes more striking when the strategy research
radar starts to probe into the corporate landscape
of emerging economies (Lau & Bruton, 2008).
In other words, when markets work smoothly
in developed economies, "the market-supporting
institutions are almost invisible," according to
McMillan (2007), who went on to argue that
when markets work poorly in emerging econo-
mies, "the absence of [strong market-supporting]
institutions is conspicuous." Coinciding with the
rise of emerging economies in the global economy
since the 1990s, more strategy researchers become
interested in these countries (Hitt et al., 2004;
Lyles & Salk, 1996; Tong, Reuer, & Peng, 2008).
Possessing a number of theoretical tools in their
research repertoire, these scholars often choose to
deploy an institutional perspective, which is be-
lieved to give them the best mileage—relative to
other theories—in advancing strategy research on
emerging economies (Wright, Filatotchev, Hos-
kisson, & Peng, 2005). The fact that an institu-
tional perspective is the most frequently drawn upon
theoretical tool speaks volumes about the particular
usefulness of this perspective when seeking to better
understand the unfolding competition in emerging
economies (Peng et al., 2008).
It is very clear that treating institutions as
"background" (or at best "control variables") will
not advance strategy research on emerging econ-
omies very far. The profound differences in insti-
tutional frameworks between emerging economies
and developed economies force scholars to pay
more attention to these differences in addition to
considering industry-based and resource-based
factors (Khanna & Yafeh, 2007; Li & Peng, 2008;
Zacharakis, McMullen, & Shepherd, 2007). For
example, recent research on the determinants of
multinational subsidiary performance documents
that (a) in developed economies, corporate (firm-
specific) effects are more critical in explaining the
variation in foreign subsidiary performance (con-
sistent with the resource-based view), and (b) in
emerging economies, country effects, which are
proxies for institutional differences, are more sa-
lient (supportive of the institution-based view)
(Makino, Isobe, & Chan, 2004, p. 1028). Overall,
such research articulates the emergence of a third
leg of the strategy tripod. Next, we outline two
core propositions derived from the institution-
based view.
Two Core Propositions
T
reating institutions as independent variables,
the institution-based view of strategy focuses
on the dynamic interaction between institu-
tions and organizations and considers strategic
choices as the outcome of such an interaction
(Peng, 2002). As shown in Figure 2, strategic
choices are not only driven by industry conditions
and firm capabilities, but are also a reflection of
the formal and informal constraints of a particular
institutional framework that managers confront (Jar-
zabkowski, 2008). As a start, this section outlines the
two core propositions emerging out of the institu-
tion-based view (Peng & Khoury, 2008).
(Boundedly) Rational Choices
While institutions serve many functions, their
most fundamental role is to reduce uncertainty
and provide meaning (Peng, 2006; Scott, 2008b).
Broadly speaking, institutions reduce uncertainty
for different actors by conditioning the ruling
norms of behaviors and defining the boundaries of
what is legitimate. Actors, in turn, rationally pur-
sue their interests and make choices within a
given institutional framework (Lee, Peng, & Bar-
ney, 2007). Uncertainty clouds the judgment of
actors, and the cues that inform decisions and
actions emerge from the relevant institutions, giv-
ing purpose and meaning for decision-makers such
as strategists (Jarzabkowski, 2008). Referring to
Scott's (1995, p. 35) three pillars, compliance or
legitimacy occurs through "(1) expedience (regu-
lative pillar), (2) social obligation (normative pil-
66 AugustAcademy of Management Perspectives
lar), or (3) on a taken-for-granted basis (cognitive
pillar)." Overall, from a rational choice perspec-
tive, we suggest:
Proposition 1: Managers and firms ratio-
nally pursue their interests and make stra-
tegic choices within the formal and infor-
mal constraints in a given institutional
framework.
In theoretical terms, the rationality discussed
here is bounded (but not perfect) rationality (Wil-
liamson, 1985). As economic players, managers
and firms are assumed to be "intendedly rational,
but only limitedly so" (Simon, 1961, xxiv, italics
original)—note the "simultaneous reference to
both intended and limited rationality" (William-
son, 1985, p. 45). One example is the determina-
tion of executive compensation. In the United
States, the (formal) competitive market for exec-
utive talents and the general (informal) tolerance
for larger income inequality have fueled rising
CEO compensation (Kaplan, 2008). In 1980, the
average U.S. CEO made approximately 42 times
the average worker's salary; in 2006, 364 times
(Walsh, 2008, p. 26). In January 2009, news broke
that Wall Street executives paid themselves $18
billion in bonuses in 2008, during which many
financial services firms were being bailed out by
hundreds of billions of taxpayer dollars (New York
Times, 2009). While labeled by President Obama
as "shameful," the executive compensation deci-
sions were understandable based on Proposition 1.
When these firms received bailout funds in late
2008, there were very few strings attached regard-
ing limits on executive bonuses. Therefore, there
was no evidence that any of the firms handing out
large bonuses violated formal law. In the absence
of formal checks and balances, the executives'
decisions were thus rational: They pursued their
interest first (Jensen & Meckling, 1976). Bounded
rationality was also clearly at play: These execu-
tives failed to appreciate the informal (but pow-
erful) norms concerning what was fair (Walsh,
2008), and thus attracted outcries from the media
and the new president.
Formal and Informal Institutions as
Compensatory Structures
Within the institutional literature, economists
have mostly focused on formal laws, rules, and
regulations (La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, & Shleifer,
2008), and sociologists have paid more attention
to informal cultures, norms, and values (DiMaggio
& Powell, 1983; Meyer & Rowan, 1977). North
(1990) and Scott (1995) supported a complemen-
tary view where research on the impact of insti-
tutions investigates both formal and informal
components. Extending these insights to strategy
research, we argue:
Figure 2
Institutions, Organizations, and Strategic Choices
Dynamic
s Organizations
Formal and Industry conditions
informal and firm-specific
Strategic
Choices
Institution
interaction
constraints resources
Source: Peng (2002, p. 253).
2009 67Peng, Sun, Pinkham, and Chen
Proposition 2: While formal and informal
institutions combine to govern firm behav-
ior, in situations where formal constraints
are unclear or fail, informal constraints
will play a larger role in reducing uncer-
tainty, providing guidance, and conferring
legitimacy and rewards to managers and
firms.
For example, in the wake of political collapse
in the former Soviet Union, numerous Russian
entrepreneurs attempted to launch and survive by
relying on social ties and connections (known as
blat) within their local networks (Puffer & Mc-
Carthy, 2007). Informal social ties facilitate eco-
nomic exchanges providing continuity for firms
weathering formal institutional transitions (Peng
& Heath, 1996). Further, research on informal
activities such as corruption also shows the impor-
tance of informal institutions in the recognition
and exploitation of opportunities (Webb, Tiha-
nyi, Ireland, & Sirmon, 2009). The common con-
dition in these comparatively unique environ-
ments is the convergence toward informal
institutions in lieu of deficient or absent formal
institutions. Specifically, there is a predominant
reliance on network-based strategies drawing on
informal relationships (Peng, 2003). In other
words, individuals and firms "often find ways of
altering the terms of their formal and informal
contracts to avoid the adverse effects of weak
[formal] contracting institutions" (Acemoglu &
Johnson, 2005, p. 949).
Many observers have the impression that rely-
ing on informal connections is a strategy relevant
only to firms in emerging economies, and that
firms in developed economies pursue only "mar-
ket-based" strategies. This is far from the truth.
Even in developed economies, formal rules make
up only a small (though important) part of insti-
tutional constraints, and informal connections are
pervasive (North, 1990).
2
Just as firms compete in
product markets, firms also fiercely compete in
political markets characterized by informal rela-
tionships (Oliver & Holzinger, 2008). The best
connected firms are able to reap huge benefits.
Business Week (2007) reported that for every dol-
lar U.S. defense firms spend on lobbying, they
reap $28, on average, in earmarks from Uncle
Sam, and more than 20 firms grab $100 or more.
Such an enviable return on investment (ROI)
compares favorably to capital expenditure (where
$1 brings in $17 in revenues) or direct marketing
(where $1 spent fetches barely $5 in sales). Basi-
cally, the institution-based view suggests that
when a firm cannot be a cost, differentiation, or
focus leader in product markets, it can still beat
the competition on other grounds—namely, the
nonmarket political arena where informal rela-
tionships hold great sway (Oliver & Holzinger,
2008).
Addressing Four Fundamental Questions
E
very discipline is unified by a set of fundamen-
tal questions, which act to define a field and to
orient the attention of scholars, students, and
practitioners in a certain direction. In strategic
management, Rumelt, Schendel, and Teece
(1994) suggested four fundamental questions: (a)
Why do firms differ? (b) How do firms behave? (c)
What determines the scope of the firm? (d) What
determines the success and failure of firms around
the globe? The industry-based and resource-based
views have addressed these important questions.
Ultimately, the influence of a new perspective
boils down to the new insights it brings on top
of what is already known. What are the new
insights brought by the institution-based view
beyond the answers provided by the industry-
based and resource-based views for these four
fundamental questions?
3
We will look at each
individually.
Why Do Firms Differ?
A fundamental assumption in strategy research,
especially from the resource-based view, is firm
2
In contrast to the "(formal) law and economics" tradition in new
institutionalism research, Dixit (2004) proposed a new subfield provoca-
tively named "lawlessness and economics" to leverage the abundance of
informal institutions not specified by formal laws and to explore their
impact on economic behavior. Dixit (2004, p. 9) suggested that "'law and
economics' and 'lawlessness and economics' can be regarded as two mutu-
ally exclusive and jointly exhaustive subfields of the larger field of eco-
nomic governance."
3
Ingram and Silverman (2002) also organized chapters in their edited
volume, The New Institutionalism in Strategic Management, according to
these four fundamental questions.
68 AugustAcademy of Management Perspectives
heterogeneity (Barney, 1991; Rumelt et al., 1994).
In every modern economy, firms, like individuals,
differ. This question of "Why do firms differ?" thus
seems obvious and hardly generates debate. How-
ever, one of the most influential institutionalism
papers, DiMaggio and Powell (1983, p. 147),
started by asking: "What makes organizations so
similar?" Interestingly, institutional insights on
why firms are so similar can help us address one of
the most fundamental questions in strategy: why
firms differ.
Much of our knowledge about "the firm" is
from research on firms in the United States and to
a lesser extent the United Kingdom, which are
embedded in what is known as Anglo-American
capitalism (Carney, Gedajlovic, & Yang, 2009;
Peng & Jiang, 2009). A smaller literature deals
with other Western countries such as Germany,
France, and Italy, collectively known as continen-
tal European capitalism. While some differences
between Anglo-American and continental Euro-
pean firms have been reported (Carr, 2005), the
contrast between these Western firms and their
Japanese counterparts is more striking (Kotha,
Dunbar, & Bird, 1995; McGuire & Dow, 2009;
Yoshikawa & McGuire, 2008). For example, in-
stead of using costly acquisitions typically found in
the West, Japanese firms extensively employ a
network form of supplier management, giving rise
to the term keiretsu (network). It turns out that
when viewed as a "big picture," firms within one
institutional environment tend to be similar
(DiMaggio & Powell, 1983), but firms differ across
institutional frameworks (Lin, Peng, Yang, & Sun,
2009).
As strategy scholars venture into emerging
economies, more puzzles emerge (Ahlstrom, Bru-
ton, & Yeh, 2007; Bruton, Dess, & Janney, 2007;
Bruton & Lau, 2008; Lau & Bruton, 2008; Li &
Peng, 2008; Young et al., 2008). For example, it is
long established that economic growth can hardly
occur in poorly regulated economies. Yet, given
China's strong economic growth and its underde-
veloped formal institutional structures (such as
ineffective courts), "how can China be achieving
rapid rates of growth, while retaining such an
institutional order?" (Boisot & Child, 1996, p.
607; see also North, 2009, p. 110). Since aggregate
firm growth leads to the growth of the economy,
strategy researchers have endeavored to provide
firm-level answers to address this intriguing puzzle.
A partial answer suggests that interpersonal net-
works (known as guanxi) cultivated by managers
may serve as informal substitutes for formal insti-
tutional support (Peng & Heath, 1996). In other
words, interpersonal relationships among manag-
ers are translated into an interfirm strategy of
relying on networks and alliances to grow the
firm, which, in the aggregate, contributes to the
growth of the economy (Peng & Luo, 2000; Ren,
Au, & Birtch, 2009).
There is a widespread belief that guanxi and the
related network-based strategies are products of
the unique Chinese (or Asian) culture that favors
collectivism. The institution-based view refutes
such reasoning by pointing out that every culture
has a word or two describing what the Chinese
call guanxi (Singh, 2007). The intensification of
informal networks during institutional transitions
is predicted by our Proposition 2, which stresses
the heavier reliance on informal constraints to
combat potential opportunism and facilitate
transactions when formal market-supporting insti-
tutions are underdeveloped. Outside China, the
intensification of informal networks as a driver for
firm strategies has been reported in Argentina
(Guillen, 2000), Indonesia (Dieleman & Sachs,
2006), India (Kedia, Mukherjee, & Lahiri, 2006),
and Russia (Puffer & McCarthy, 2007). Per Prop-
osition 1, managers and firms behave rationally
under these circumstances. Given the prevalence
of institutional nuance in these settings, industry-
based and resource-based views alone will not
foster a sufficiently deep or adequate understand-
ing of the differences between firms (Khanna &
Yafeh, 2007).
Further, the institution-based view predicts
that the more formal market-supporting institu-
tions develop in emerging economies, the more
we can expect a reduced reliance on informal
network-based strategies and a heavier reliance
on arm's-length market-based strategies (Peng,
2003). The history of modern economic develop-
ment throughout the Western world corroborates
this view (Greif, 2006). Preliminary evidence
from China's recent institutional transitions
2009 69Peng, Sun, Pinkham, and Chen
(Guthrie, 1998; Li, Poppo, & Zhou, 2008; Zhou,
Poppo, & Yang, 2008) is also supportive of this
view.
How Do Firms Behave?
Each of the three legs of the strategy tripod (as
shown in Figure 1) sheds light on this question.
The industry-based view suggests that the strategic
task is mainly to stake out a position that is less
vulnerable relative to the five forces within an
industry. The resource-based view posits that firm-
specific capabilities differentiate successful firms
from failing ones.
The institution-based view adds by arguing
that in addition to industry- and firm-level con-
ditions, firms also need to take into account the
influences of formal and informal rules of the
game. For example, consider the Japanese phar-
maceutical industry. The success of innovative
Japanese automobile and electronics products
around the world has led many to naively believe
that all Japanese firms are "innovative." The in-
stitution-based view refutes this thinking, by
pointing out that world-class innovative pharma-
ceutical firms are all Western. Why is there not a
single Japanese pharmaceutical firm that is world-
class? The reason is institutional. The health care
system in Japan does not reward innovative new
drugs (Mahlich, 2009). The Ministry of Health
negotiates drug prices with firms. However, once
fixed, prices are not allowed to rise during drugs'
prespecified shelf life. If prices remain the same
but manufacturing costs decrease because of econ-
omies of scale, then the oldest drugs, not the new-
est, command the highest margins in Japan (Peng,
2009, p. 101). Thus, given these rules of the game
(Proposition 1), Japanese pharmaceutical manag-
ers and firms, being rational, find little incentive
to aggressively invest in R&D. In contrast, West-
ern firms face an institutional environment that
rewards "wonder drugs" with the highest margins,
thus fueling their R&D-intensive strategy (Lu,
Tsang, & Peng, 2008).
In summary, the example of Japanese pharma-
ceutical firms suggests that institutions are not just
"background" conditions and that not all major
pharmaceutical firms should pursue an R&D-in-
tensive strategy. Within the same industry, tre-
mendous diversity exists due to institutional dif-
ferences.
What Determines the Scope of the Firm?
4
The scope of the firm refers to the product and/or
geographic scope of the firm (Peng & Delios,
2006). Strategy researchers have mostly focused
on the product scope, and international business
scholars have paid more attention to the geo-
graphic scope (Collinson & Rugman, 2007; Lu &
Beamish, 2004; Rugman, 2005). Given our focus
on strategy in this article, this section outlines
work that deals with product scope.
In the United States, the product scope of the
largest Fortune 500 firms has experienced signifi-
cant changes in the postwar era (Davis, Diek-
mann, & Tinsley, 1994). From the 1950s to the
1970s, a broad scope based on a large number of
unrelated product markets was deemed valuable.
However, the consensus since the 1980s favors
product-related diversification and discredits con-
glomeration. This change has been documented
by the dramatic reversal in investor sentiments
toward conglomerate mergers and acquisitions—
"positive in the 1960s, neutral in the 1970s, and
negative in the 1980s" (Matsusaka, 1993, p. 358).
The dominant trend since the 1980s has brought
U.S. firms to focus more on core competencies. In
many respects, the postwar decades were "a round-
trip for corporate America" (Shleifer & Vishny,
1991, p. 51).
How to make sense of this round-trip? Both the
industry-based and resource-based views focus on
product relatedness. The industry-based view
deals primarily with the risks associated with a
single-industry strategy and calls for some moder-
ate diversification for risk reduction purposes. The
resource-based view emphasizes synergy in related
industries and products. Both views converge to
an argument in favor of product-related diversifi-
cation, as opposed to conglomeration. However,
both views have a hard time explaining why con-
glomeration took place in the first place and then
4
This section focuses on the determinants of the scope of the firm in
developed economies, specifically the United States. See Khanna and Yafeh
(2007), Lee, Peng, and Lee (2008), Peng and Delios (2006), and Peng, Lee,
and Wang (2005) for explications on how the institution-based view sheds
light on what is behind diversification strategies in emerging economies.
70 AugustAcademy of Management Perspectives
why the round-trip was undertaken. There are two
rival interpretations. The first is that the con-
glomeration strategy of the 1960s was a good idea
back then, but was no longer a good idea more
recently. The second is that conglomeration,
whose overall performance was dismal, was a mis-
take from the start, and was corrected more re-
cently—in other words, "corporate America took
a 30-year detour away from efficiency" (Shleifer &
Vishny, 1991, p. 54).
The institution-based view suggests a plausible
explanation tapping into both formal and infor-
mal aspects of the institutional environment
(Peng, Lee, & Wang, 2005; Wan & Hoskisson,
2003). Between the 1950s and the 1970s, the
federal government, through a set of formal con-
straints, inadvertently promoted conglomeration
(Fligstein, 1990). The post-1950 antitrust policies
eliminated horizontal and vertical mergers within
the same industry as viable growth strategies be-
cause they were viewed as "anticompetitive." Re-
luctant to pay out the high cash flows as divi-
dends, managers and firms seeking growth were
forced to look beyond their primary industry by
engaging in unrelated acquisitions, which would
not be challenged by antitrust authorities. In
other words, our Proposition 1 suggests that man-
agers and firms in an earlier era behaved ratio-
nally given the formal institutional constraints.
In terms of the influence of the informal insti-
tutions, the 1950s was the first decade during
which MBA education took off in the United
States. As more MBAs, trained to be multi-
industry general management specialists, en-
tered corporate America, they led to an infor-
mal but powerful norm that viewed a firm as an
economic entity—regardless of its industry
membership—in search of profits, as opposed to
a producer dedicated to a particular industry
(Fligstein, 1990). In short, conglomeration was
in vogue (Abrahamson, 1996), and most large
corporations deviant from this norm were forced
to conform (Davis et al., 1994).
However, by the early 1980s, the formal con-
straints that favored conglomeration changed sub-
stantially. Intraindustry mergers were no longer
critically scrutinized by the Reagan administra-
tion, thus allowing for acquisitions of rivals within
the same industry.
5
In contrast with the way con-
glomeration was facilitated by heightened anti-
trust policy, the movement for more related diver-
sification, typically within the same industry, has
been enabled by more relaxed antitrust enforce-
ment since the 1980s (Shleifer & Vishny, 1991).
Moreover, we saw a new generation of MBAs
influenced by the newly coined idea of "share-
holder capitalism" (Jensen & Meckling, 1976).
The rise of "shareholder capitalism" directly cor-
related with the demise of the previous legitimacy-
enhancing informal norms in favor of conglomer-
ation (Davis et al., 1994). Consequently, the new
norm—or "fashion" (Abrahamson, 1996)—is to
focus on core product areas.
Overall, the curious round-trip of the product
scope of the firm over time in the United States
cannot be adequately explained by the industry-
based and resource-based views only. The institu-
tion-based view adds a significant piece to the
puzzle by drawing on both formal and informal
aspects of the institutional framework during post-
war decades (Peng et al., 2005). It is the combined
impact and change of these institutional con-
straints that is behind the evolution of the scope
of the firm (Lee, Peng, & Lee, 2008).
What Determines the Success and Failure of Firms
Around the Globe?
This focus on performance, more than anything
else, defines the strategy field (Hambrick &
Chen, 2008; Peng, 2006, 2009; Rumelt et al.,
1994). All three major perspectives that form
the strategy tripod ultimately seek to answer this
question. The industry-based view posits that the
degree of competitiveness in an industry largely
determines firm performance (Porter, 1980). The
resource-based view suggests that firm-specific ca-
5
This change was not because the U.S. government suddenly changed
its mind. It was in part because of efforts made by new institutionalism
scholars, who promoted "a growing appreciation for transaction costs"
(Williamson, 1985, p. 365). These scholars argued for the efficiency ben-
efits of vertical mergers. If antitrust authorities do not allow a supplier and
a buyer to merge and thus force them to constantly negotiate with each
other, the additional transaction costs are likely to translate into higher
prices for consumers, who will ultimately suffer. Internalization through
mergers and integration may reduce some of these transaction costs and
benefit consumers (Williamson, 1975).
2009 71Peng, Sun, Pinkham, and Chen
pabilities drive performance differences (Barney,
1991).
The institution-based view argues that institu-
tional forces also provide an answer to differences
in firm performance. As firms increasingly venture
abroad, it is difficult to imagine firms that fail to
do their "homework" by getting to know the var-
ious formal and informal rules of the game in
overseas markets will emerge as winners (Glober-
man & Shapiro, 2009; Hitt et al., 2004; Luo &
Peng, 1999). This point is obviously crucial for
firms doing business internationally. However,
firms doing business domestically also need to ex-
ercise significant due diligence regarding the rules
of the game to ensure good performance; other-
wise, firms can be burned in their own home
country. In October 2008, India's Tata Group,
developer of the critically acclaimed Tata Nano
automobile that would retail for just $2,500 (the
cheapest car in the world), painfully scratched its
plans to manufacture the Nano in West Bengal
(Economist, 2008). Evidently Tata's plans, which
would generate thousands of jobs in West Bengal,
failed to take into account the hostile state gov-
ernment and farmers who resented the loss of
farmland for the Nano factory.
Overall, although different schools of thought
often debate with each other, the true determi-
nants of firm performance probably involve a com-
bination of these three-pronged forces, thus calling
for a strategy tripod perspective (Brouthers et al.,
2008; Gao, Murray, Kotabe, & Lu, 2009; Meyer,
Estrin, Bhaumik, & Peng, 2009; Yamakawa, Peng,
& Deeds, 2008; Yang, Jiang, Kang, & Ke, 2009).
In a first comprehensive quantitative test measur-
ing the impact of industry-based, resource-based,
and institution-based variables on firm strategy
and performance, Gao et al. (2009) found that
institution-based variables assert significant ef-
fects on exporters' strategy and performance
"above and beyond the impact of firm competen-
cies and industry factors." Overall, the institution-
based view complements the existing industry-
based and resource-based views to collectively
sustain a strategy tripod.
In summary, these four questions represent
some of the most fundamental puzzles in strategy.
While other questions can be raised, they all re-
late in one way or another to these four (Rumelt
et al., 1994). The institution-based view adds sig-
nificantly new insights to these questions by
bringing institutions to the forefront of the re-
search agenda (Ingram & Silverman, 2002; Peng
et al., 2008).
Discussion
Contributions
B
y arguing that the institution-based view has
emerged as the third leg for a strategy tripod,
this article makes three contributions: (a) We
identify the roots of the institution-based view,
(b) we outline the two core propositions that go
beyond the relatively simplistic "institutions mat-
ter" assertion, and (c) we illustrate how the insti-
tution-based view adds significant insights to the
four fundamental questions in strategy above and
beyond what we already know based on the in-
dustry-based and resource-based views.
McKinley, Mone, and Moon (1999) argued
that whether a particular theory gains widespread
acceptance depends on its continuity, novelty,
and scope. We believe that the institution-based
view excels in these three attributes, thereby
propelling its recent rise as the third leading per-
spective in strategy. First, by extending new insti-
tutionalism into strategy research, the institution-
based view exemplifies a great deal of continuity
from the larger social sciences literature (Ingram
& Silverman, 2002). Strategy researchers are fa-
miliar with certain elements of new institutional-
ism, such as transaction cost economics (TCE).
Further, the institution-based view exhibits strong
continuity with existing research by being able to
address strategy's four fundamental questions
head on.
Second, by emphasizing the path-dependent
nature of the evolution of institutions and its
impact on strategy, the institution-based view
brings significant novelty to strategy research. Ex-
amples include the puzzling growth of economic
development in China, the curious lack of world-
class innovative pharmaceutical firms in Japan,
and the mind-boggling round-trip of the product
scope of the firm over time in the United States.
New institutionalism research outside strategic
72 AugustAcademy of Management Perspectives
management often examines economic and orga-
nizational outcomes from the deep past (Greif,
2006; North, 1990, 2005).
6
This approach con-
trasts sharply with the usual "best practice" in
strategy research coming from the industry-based
and resource-based traditions that ignore histories
and contexts (Narayanan & Fahey, 2005). Ac-
cording to Ingram and Silverman (2002, p. 6):
The treatment of history in the new institutionalism
stands in sharp contrast to the normal practice in research
on business strategy. Strategy often suffers from a tyr-
anny of the here and now, a desire to celebrate contem-
porary phenomena and slight historical ones. This ahis-
toricism is one reason why research in strategy struggles
for social-scientific legitimacy. By reveling in current af-
fairs and de-emphasizing their underpinnings in the past,
strategy scholarship often undermines its own claims to
develop explanations that transcend their contemporary
context. In other words, the field of strategy struggles to
develop good theory, because it downplays temporal tran-
sitivity and generalizability.
It is not surprising that scholars who focus on
strategic choices during institutional transitions in
emerging economies are among the first groups of
strategy researchers to pay attention to the impor-
tance of contexts (Luo & Peng, 1999; Peng &
Heath, 1996). Simply focusing on traditional in-
dustry-based and resource-based variables will not
paint a complete picture (Meyer et al., 2009), thus
triggering the quest to probe deeper into institu-
tion-based insights. Of course, scholars interested
in developed economies have long argued for
more attention to institutions (Dobbin & Dowd,
1997; Fligstein, 1990; Oliver, 1997). Both streams
of work have now converged to lead to the insti-
tution-based view.
The institution-based view also excels in its
scope. The many possible institution-based fac-
tors that may influence firm strategy and per-
formance allow for numerous ways of theorizing
and testing, resulting in an expanding and cu-
mulative body of knowledge. As examples, we
use three diverse areas to illustrate the broad
scope of the institution-based view. First, the
institution-based view can add significant in-
sights to the industry-based and resource-based
views by specifying in what contexts and under
what circumstances certain capabilities in cer-
tain industries add value (Brouthers et al., 2008;
Dacin et al., 2007). Second, the institution-
based view can also benefit from cross-fertiliza-
tion with the evolutionary perspective, whose
leading question is "How do firms coevolve with
their environment?" (Lewin & Volberda, 1999,
p. 520). Third, research on multinational enter-
prises (MNEs) can be further propelled by the
institution-based view (Dunning & Lundan,
2008; Kostova, Roth, & Dacin, 2008).
While the institution-based view adds to the
strategy literature, it also contributes to the
larger new institutionalism literature. Focusing
on firm-level strategy, the institution-based
view contributes to institutional economics by
connecting its micro and macro branches. The
micro TCE branch has taken the macro insti-
tutional environment as a given "background"
and focused more on microanalytical aspects
such as opportunism (Williamson, 1975, 1985).
The macro branch of institutional economics
(Greif, 2006; La Porta et al., 2008; North, 1990)
has reminded us that such "background" needs
to be brought to the forefront. Yet institutional
economics tends to talk about rulers and inter-
est groups on the one hand and economic out-
comes on the other hand—leaving the interme-
diate, firm-level strategy-making processes
largely unexplored. In other words, institutional
economics has not focused on how individual
firms respond to institutional frameworks from a
strategy perspective. The institution-based view
of strategy, therefore, directly connects the
firm-level strategy-making processes with both
the micro and macro branches of institutional
economics.
The institution-based view of strategy also
adds to the sociologically oriented institutional
theory by demonstrating the benefits of inte-
grating with efficiency-oriented research. Di-
Maggio and Powell (1991, p. 8) suggested that
the "new institutionalism...comprises a re-
jection of rational-actor models" often found in
efficiency-based research (italics added). While
such a perspective may make sense when study-
ing educational institutions and public bureau-
6
For example, North, Wallis, and Weingast (2006) recently developed
a conceptual framework for interpreting "recorded human history."
2009 73Peng, Sun, Pinkham, and Chen
cracies, where sociologically driven new insti-
tutionalism research initially arose (Meyer &
Rowan, 1977), more recent work has advised us
not to pit "strategic and institutional," "substan-
tive and symbolic," and "economic and social"
factors against each other (Powell, 1996, p.
295). In other words, initial work may have
"overstated" organizations' urge to adopt super-
ficial conformity at the expense of their quest
for efficiency (Scott, 2008a, p. 431). As insti-
tutional theory moves away from schools and
bureaucracies to assert its influence in strategy,
a focus on efficiency outcomes, which is a hall-
mark of strategy research, becomes necessary
and enriches institutional theory (Oliver, 1997;
Scott, 1987, 2008a).
Finally, the institution-based view of strategy
also holds potential to push the boundaries of the
emerging literature on the varieties of capitalism
(VOC) (Hall & Soskice, 2001) as well as corpo-
rate social responsibility (CSR) (Husted & Allen,
2006). The VOC literature seeks to understand
the diverse topography of institutional landscapes
(Carney et al., 2009; Jackson & Deeg, 2008). On
the other hand, the CSR literature posits that the
relationship between basic economic conditions
and corporate behavior is mediated by institu-
tional constraints (Campbell, 2007). For example,
the recent recall of certain toys made in China
reminds us that firms face the possibility of losing
their legitimacy (and business) if they ignore their
basic CSR concerning product safety (Peng &
Chen, 2009). Both VOC and CSR can be en-
hanced by integrating with the institution-based
view of strategy.
Why the "Institution-Based" View Label for
Strategy?
One interesting point to discuss is why we use
the particular label "institution-based view." Is
it the same as an "institutional view"? Is it the
same as "institutional economics"? Or "institu-
tional theory"? What is the value of a new label
for strategy?
The adoption of the term "institution-based
view," coined by Peng (2002), stems from the
confusion in the literature and the decision to
avoid an interdisciplinary turf battle.
7
First, the
proliferation of "institutional" research has pro-
duced some confusion. In our (impartial scholarly)
view, broadly speaking, any theory that invokes a
new institutionalism framing can be legitimately
labeled "institutional theory." However, in the
literature the term "institutional theory" increas-
ingly refers to the sociological version of the insti-
tutional literature (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983).
The economic version, represented by North
(1990), is often labeled simply "institutional eco-
nomics." Because of the interdisciplinary nature of
strategy research, using either label ("institutional
theory" or "institutional economics") would cause
confusion. Furthermore, there has been significant
interpenetration between economics and sociol-
ogy. For example, Scott (1995) has long acknowl-
edged North's (1990) influence in economic soci-
ology. North's (2005) more recent work has
explicitly discussed "stickiness" (resistance to
change) as part of cognition, which notably bears
reciprocal correspondence to Scott's (1995) third
(cognitive) pillar. Some economists have now
worked on typically "sociological" constructs such
as culture and social capital (Guiso, Sapienza, &
Zingales, 2006) and drawn extensively on the
sociological literature. Therefore, in response to
reviewer pressures from both sides, Peng (2003, p.
276) clarified:
Although the economic (e.g., North, 1990) and socio-
logical (e.g., Scott, 1995) versions of institutional theory
have some differences, they are broadly complementary
(Scott, 1995). Following Peng and Heath (1996,
p. 499), who suggest that "a combination of the two is
natural" for management research, here I draw on the
best available insights from the institutional literature,
regardless of the disciplinary background.
7
During the review process, Peng and Heath (1996), Peng (2003), and
Peng et al. (2005) were pushed by some economically oriented reviewers to
declare that our theoretical background was "institutional economics,"
which should have nothing to do with (the sociological) "institutional
theory." At the same time, we were pushed by some sociologically oriented
reviewers to declare our "party line" by following the sociological version of
"institutional theory." As part of management scholarship, our work was
indeed inspired by both the economic and sociological versions of the
institutional literature. To remain intellectually honest, we felt uncomfort-
able declaring allegiance to any disciplinary "party line" at the expense of
another discipline. Of course, other strategy scholars may choose not to
blend these lines of reasoning in order to strive for greater consistency—at
least in relation to the literature in one discipline (Estrin, Baghdasaryan, &
Meyer, 2009).
74 AugustAcademy of Management Perspectives
Innovation is often forced by necessity. The in-
novative "institution-based view" label is forced
by the necessity to get the papers accepted by
reviewers while advancing strategy research, and
is the fruit of an interdisciplinary dialogue or
"trade" (Peng, 2004). The value of the new label
is that this is a progeny the strategy field can lay
claim to as its own (Peng & Khoury, 2008). We
need to have the self-confidence to declare that
we are doing neither second-class economics nor
second-class sociology, but first-class strategy re-
search. Advocated by Peng (2002, 2006, 2009;
Peng et al., 2008), the "institution-based view"
label has helped us differentiate from existing
work in economics and sociology, and has at-
tracted a series of additional papers that carry this
research forward (Gao et al., 2009; Lee et al.,
2008; Lu et al., 2008; Mahlich, 2009; Meyer et al.,
2009; Peng & Jiang, 2009; Peng & Pleggenkuhle-
Miles, 2009; Yamakawa et al., 2008; Yang et al.,
2009).
Future Directions
Institution-based research in strategy is likely to
develop in at least three directions. First, the
institution-based view, for the first time, enables
strategy scholars to confront important public pol-
icy issues. Because institutional frameworks have
typically been assumed to be "background," strat-
egy researchers have largely shied away from im-
portant public policy issues (Barney, 2005). De-
spite the popularity of TCE in strategy research,
we as a field have almost totally failed to pay
attention to Williamson's (1975) subtitle: Anti-
trust Implications.
8
The upshot? Microsoft, an oth-
erwise brilliant firm, the poster child for the in-
dustry-based and resource-based views, ended up
in court for alleged antitrust violations. Its alleged
crime? Not voluntarily helping its competitors (!).
It is clear that Microsoft strategists trained by
the industry-based and resource-based views
failed to appreciate the rules of the game that—
rightly or wrongly—govern a leading firm dif-
ferently than nonleading firms. While Mi-
crosoft, its accusers, and its defenders could
vehemently argue (Liebowitz & Margolis, 1999;
Schmalensee, 2000), Microsoft's failure to in-
clude antitrust issues on its strategy radar
screen, until it was sued, was an evident failure
in strategic due diligence. In the long run, strat-
egy's tendency to eschew engagement with ma-
jor public policy issues may keep the field on the
sidelines in debates about issues in which it can
potentially contribute (Peng, 2003, p. 275). We
hope the institution-based view will help over-
come this tendency.
A second direction is to study how firms adapt
to institutional changes and regulatory shifts
(Peng, 2003; Walker, Madson, & Carini 2002).
The ongoing global economic crisis and firms'
strategic responses will prove to be fertile ground
for such research. For example, some U.S. politi-
cians blame the current financial crisis on Con-
gress' 1999 deregulatory decision to repeal part of
the Glass-Steagall Act of 1933 and a 2004 SEC
rule that allows more leverage, and now call for
more regulation. Strategy scholars need to answer
why five leading investment banks folded while
most hedge funds and private-equity companies
have had fewer problems under the same deregu-
lation policy. Why have GM and Ford sold large
numbers of their desirably fuel-efficient cars in
Europe but not in the United States? Clearly, it is
not because they do not possess capabilities in
fuel-efficient technologies. Their lack of incentive
to market such cars in the United States is under-
pinned by an institutional framework character-
ized by lower taxes on gasoline. Conversely, their
aggressive marketing of such cars in Europe is
fueled by another institutional framework cen-
tered on heavier taxes on gasoline and stronger
discouragement of consumption and pollution
(Wall Street Journal, 2008b).
A third direction is to develop stronger mea-
sures of institutions, probably first arising out of
descriptive, qualitative, and historical research
but ultimately quantifying their dimensions (La
Porta et al., 2008). Criticizing the literature, Go-
mez-Mejia, Wiseman, and Dykes (2005, p. 1512)
argued:
8
A complete search of all Strategic Management Journal publications
since its first volume in 1980 yielded only a grand total of one (!) article
with "antitrust" in its title (Clougherty, 2005) and one more article with
"antitrust" in its abstract (Shleifer & Vishny, 1991).
2009 75Peng, Sun, Pinkham, and Chen
The danger of extending institutional theory too broadly,
however, such that each institutional context is different,
is that our application of the theory becomes atheoretical,
leading us down a path toward highly stylized idiosyncratic
examples that prevent the development of a generalizable
theory of the firm. In our view, there must be a balance
between recognizing unique contextual factors and the
theory.
We agree. We are not advocating "dense descrip-
tions" and "case studies" for every paper. The
ultimate aim for proponents of the institution-
based view will be to demonstrate how institution-
based variables matter. The potential institutional
variables include institution relatedness (Peng et
al., 2005), institutional distance (Chan, Isobe, &
Makino, 2008; Estrin, Baghdasaryan, & Meyer,
2009; Xu & Shenkar, 2002), legal origins (La
Porta et al., 2008), and corruption indexes (Cu-
ervo-Cazurra & Genc, 2008; Lee & Oh, 2007).
However, institution-based variables tend to be
coarse-grained and universal—at least within one
context. In other words, since the rules of the
game within one institutional framework, in the-
ory, apply to all firms within its jurisdiction, how
can certain firms better use these rules to outper-
form the rest? For example, intellectual property
regimes centered on patents as a specific rule of
the game are generally argued to facilitate more
innovation and better performance. However,
empirical links among R&D, patenting, and per-
formance of specific firms are tenuous (Khoury &
Peng, 2008).
It is here we need to reemphasize that the
institution-based view is one of the three legs of
the strategy tripod— but not the only leg. It is in
combination with the industry-based and resource-
based views that the institution-based view can
add its value (Gao et al., 2009; Meyer et al., 2009;
Oliver, 1997). In the case of patenting, the indus-
try-based view suggests that patents contribute
more to leading firms in certain industries (such as
pharmaceuticals) than in other industries (such as
electronics) (Bessen & Meurer, 2008, p. 18). The
resource-based view argues that it is not capabili-
ties in R&D per se that drive performance (Git-
telman, 2008). It may be the firm-specific, in-
house patent law expertise, in combination with
R&D prowess, that leads to superior firm perfor-
mance (Somaya, Williamson, & Zhang, 2007).
Finally, in terms of teaching and learning, we
believe that incorporating the institution-based
view will make the strategy teaching and learning
experience more insightful, realistic, and bal-
anced. Table 2 outlines a series of important in-
stitution-based topics and debates that are typi-
cally missed or ignored in strategy teaching at the
undergraduate and MBA levels. We recommend
that they be added. Otherwise, we are doing the
practitioner community a disservice by training
Table 2
Institution-Based Topics Recommended for Strategic Management Teaching
Areas in Strategy Teaching Recommended Institution-Based Topics and Debates
Industry-based view (five forces) ● Formal: Competition policy (e.g., Microsoft's antitrust issues)
● Informal: Norms governing a cost leadership strategy (e.g., the Wal-Mart effect)
Resource-based view ● Government intervention in the determination of value (e.g., bailouts in 2008–2009)
Market entry ● Antidumping laws in host countries
Competitive dynamics ● Collusion versus competition
Strategic alliances ● Antitrust considerations (especially when collaborating with competitors)
Mergers and acquisitions ● Antitrust scrutiny, which may come from abroad (e.g., the proposed merger of two U.S.-based firms, GE and
Honeywell, was torpedoed by the EU)
Product diversification ● Persistence of business groups (conglomerates) in emerging economies
Organization structure ● Location of key units (such as R&D)—do they have to be in the home country?
Corporate governance ● Formal laws and informal norms governing executive compensation (e.g., Wall Street bonuses in 2008–2009)
Corporate social responsibility ● Formal: Environmental regulations ("race to the bottom" versus "race to the top")
● Informal: Norms governing domestic and overseas social responsibility
Source: Adapted from text in Peng (2009).
76 AugustAcademy of Management Perspectives
would-be strategists solely in the tradition of in-
dustry-based and resource-based views. Imagine
the shock that Microsoft's strategists experienced
when informed that they were being sued by an-
titrust authorities, after these strategists had
done everything "right" by the playbooks of the
industry-based and resource-based views.
Teaching of the industry-based view and re-
lated topics such as competitive dynamics, strate-
gic alliances, product diversification, and acquisi-
tions needs to take into account the role of formal
competition (antitrust) policies (Clougherty,
2005). Teaching topics such as five forces, corpo-
rate governance, and CSR will be significantly
enriched if we engage students with debates on
the informal (but powerful) norms regarding a
variety of issues. For example, how low can a
Wal-Mart-type low-cost strategy go without at-
tracting public criticism? How high can executive
compensation be set without provoking media
outcries (Kaplan, 2008; Walsh, 2008)? How much
investment can be made overseas without endan-
gering firms' social responsibility toward domestic
employees, communities, and governments (Peng
& Pleggenkuhle-Miles, 2009)? As a dynamic, fast-
moving field, strategy will have no shortage of
new institution-based topics and debates that can
be brought into the classroom.
Conclusion
T
hirty years is a tender age for the relatively new
discipline of strategic management (Hambrick
& Chen, 2008). The latest leading theoretical
perspective in strategy—the institution-based
view—has an even younger age of approximately
ten years within the strategy literature. Overall,
the rise of the institution-based view can be
viewed from a simple SWOT analysis. In terms of
O and T, externally, the rise of new institution-
alism throughout the social sciences has created
an opportunity. Internally, further development of
the strategy field has been threatened by a lack of
attention to crucial contexts exhibited by the
existing literature. Strategy as a field needs to
embrace the proposition that "institutions matter"
and to push forward to shed light on how institu-
tions matter. In terms of S and W, the institution-
based view excels in its continuity, novelty, and
scope as its leading strengths. Researchers also need
to be aware of its weaknesses (such as being too
broad and too encompassing) and endeavor to
overcome them.
In short, it is the emergence of the third leg
that sustains a strategy tripod. If strategy is truly a
discipline about the "big picture" (as many of us
like to say in our teaching), then the institution-
based view, based on its explicit link between
broad institutional issues and firm strategy and
performance, will help substantiate strategy's "big
picture" claim.
More than 20 years ago, Scott (1987) labeled
the institutional theory literature to be in its ad-
olescence.
9
Within the field of strategic manage-
ment, we can make the case that the institution-
based view is currently in its adolescence as the
third leading perspective. In conclusion, it is use-
ful to quote Scott's (1987, p. 510) conclusion:
Adolescents have their awkwardness and their acne, but
they also embody energy and promise. They require en-
couragement as well as criticism if they are to channel
their energies in productive directions and achieve their
promise.
References
Abrahamson, E. (1996). Management fashion. Academy of
Management Review, 21(1), 254–285.
Acemoglu, D., & Johnson, S. (2005). Unbundling institu-
tions. Journal of Political Economy, 113(5), 949–995.
Ahlstrom, D., Bruton, G. D., & Yeh, K. S. (2007). Venture
capital in China: Past, present, and future. Asia Pacific
Journal of Management, 24(3), 247–268.
Barney, J. B. (1991). Firm resources and sustainable com-
petitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17(1), 99–
120.
Barney, J. B. (2001). Is the resource-based "view" a useful
perspective for strategic management research? Yes.
Academy of Management Review, 26(1), 41–56.
Barney, J. B. (2005). Should strategic management research
engage public policy debates? Academy of Management
Journal, 48(6), 945–948.
Bessen, J., & Meurer, M. J. (2008). Do patents perform like
property? Academy of Management Perspectives, 22(3),
8–20.
Boisot, M., & Child, J. (1996). From fiefs to clans and
network capitalism: Explaining China's emerging eco-
nomic order. Administrative Science Quarterly, 41(4),
600– 628.
Brouthers, K., Brouthers, L., & Werner, S. (2008). Re-
9
Scott (2008a) recently labeled the institutional theory literature in
sociology as "approaching adulthood."
2009 77Peng, Sun, Pinkham, and Chen
source-based advantages in an international context.
Journal of Management, 34(2), 189–217.
Bruton, G. D., Dess, G., & Janney, J. (2007). Knowledge
management in technology-focused firms in emerging
economies: Caveats on capabilities, networks, and real
options. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 24(2), 115–
130.
Bruton, G. D., & Lau, C. M. (2008). Asian management
research: Status today and future outlook. Journal of
Management Studies, 45, 636–659.
Business Week (2007). Inside the hidden world of earmarks.
September 17, 56–59.
Campbell, J. L. (2007). Why would corporations behave in
socially responsible ways? An institutional theory of cor-
porate social responsibility. Academy of Management Re-
view, 32(3), 946–967.
Carney, M., Gedajlovic, E., & Yang, X. (2009). Varieties of
Asian capitalism: Toward an institutional theory of
Asian enterprise. Asia Pacific Journal of Management,
26(3), 361–380.
Carr, C. (2005). Are German, Japanese, and Anglo-Saxon
strategic decision styles still divergent in the context of
globalization? Journal of Management Studies, 42(6),
1155–1188.
Chan, C., Isobe, T., & Makino, S. (2008). Which country
matters? Institutional development and foreign affiliate
performance. Strategic Management Journal, 29(11),
1179–1205.
Clougherty, J. (2005). Antitrust holdup, cross-national in-
stitutional variation, and corporate political strategy im-
plications for domestic mergers in a global context. Stra-
tegic Management Journal, 26(8), 769–790.
Collinson, S., & Rugman, A. M. (2007). The regional
character of Asian multinational enterprises. Asia Pacific
Journal of Management, 24(4), 429–446.
Cuervo-Cazurra, A., & Genc, M. (2008). Transforming
disadvantages into advantages: Developing-country
MNEs in the least developed countries. Journal of Inter-
national Business Studies, 39, 957–979.
Dacin, M. T., Oliver, C., & Roy, J. P. (2007). The legiti-
macy of strategic alliances: An institutional perspective.
Strategic Management Journal, 28(2), 167–187.
Davis, G., Diekmann, K., & Tinsley, C. (1994). The decline
and fall of the conglomerate firm in the 1990s: The
deinstitutionalization of an organizational form. Ameri-
can Sociological Review, 59(4), 547–570.
Dess, G. G., & Beard, D. (1984). Dimensions of organiza-
tional task environments. Administrative Science Quar-
terly, 29(1), 52–73.
Dieleman, M., & Sachs, W. (2006). Oscillating between a
relationship-based and a market-based model: The Salim
Group. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 23(4), 521–
536.
DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. (1983). The iron cage
revisited: Institutional isomorphism and collective ratio-
nality in organizational fields. American Sociological Re-
view, 48(2), 147–160.
DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. (1991). Introduction. In
W. W. Powell & P. J. DiMaggio (Eds.), The new institu-
tionalism in organizational analysis. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Dixit, A. (2004). Lawlessness and economics. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Dobbin, F., & Dowd, T. J. (1997). How policy shapes
competition: Early railroad foundings in Massachusetts.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 42(3), 501–529.
Dunning, J. H., & Lundan, S. M. (2008). Institutions and
the OLI paradigm of the multinational enterprise. Asia
Pacific Journal of Management, 25(4), 573–594.
Economist. (2008, October 11). A new home for the Nano.
Retrieved October 26, 2008, from http://www.economist.
com/business/displayStory.cfm?source ⫽ hptextfeature&
story_id⫽12381021.
Estrin, S., Baghdasaryan, D., & Meyer, K. E. (2009). The
impact of institutional and human resource distance on
international entry strategies. Journal of Management
Studies (in press).
Fligstein, N. (1990). The transformation of corporate control.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Gao, G. Y., Murray, J. Y., Kotabe, M., & Lu, J. (2009). A
strategy tripod perspective on export behavior: Evidence
from domestic and foreign firms based in an emerging
economy. Journal of International Business Studies (in
press).
Gittelman, M. (2008). A note on the value of patents as
indicators of innovation: Implications for management
research. Academy of Management Perspectives, 22(3),
21–27.
Globerman, S., & Shapiro, D. (2009). Economic and stra-
tegic considerations surrounding Chinese FDI in the
United States. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 26(1),
163–183.
Gomez-Mejia, L., Wiseman, R. M., & Dykes, B. J. (2005).
Agency problems in diverse contexts: A global perspec-
tive. Journal of Management Studies, 42(7), 1507–1517.
Greif, A. (2006). Institutions and the path to the modern
economy. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Guillen, M. (2000). Business groups in emerging economies:
A resource-based view. Academy of Management Journal,
43(3), 362–380.
Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2006). Does culture
affect economic outcomes? Journal of Economic Perspec-
tives, 20(2), 23–48.
Guthrie, D. (1998). The declining significance of guanxi
in China's economic transition. China Quarterly,
154(June), 254–282.
Hall, P. A., & Soskice, D. (Eds.). (2001). Varieties of
capitalism: The institutional foundations of comparative ad-
vantage. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.
Hambrick, D. C., & Chen, M. J. (2008). New academic
fields as admittance-seeking social movements: The case
of strategic management. Academy of Management Re-
view, 33(1), 32–54.
Hitt, M. A., Ahlstrom, D., Dacin, M. T., Levitas, E., &
Svobodina, L. (2004). The institutional effects on stra-
tegic alliance partner selection in transition economies:
China vs. Russia. Organization Science, 15(2), 173–185.
Husted, B. W., & Allen, D. B. (2006). Corporate social
responsibility in the multinational enterprise: Strategic
78 AugustAcademy of Management Perspectives
and institutional approaches. Journal of International
Business Studies, 37(6), 838–849.
Ingram, P., & Silverman, B. (2002). Introduction. In P.
Ingram & B. Silverman (Eds.), The new institutionalism in
strategic management (pp. 1–30). Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Jackson, G., & Deeg, R. (2008). Comparing capitalisms:
Understanding institutional diversity and its implica-
tions for international business. Journal of International
Business Studies, 39(4), 540–561.
Jarzabkowski, P. (2008). Shaping strategy as a structuration
process. Academy of Management Journal, 51(4), 621–
650.
Jensen, M., & Meckling, W. (1976). Theory of the firm:
Managerial behavior, agency costs, and ownership struc-
ture. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305–360.
Kaplan, S. N. (2008). Are U.S. CEOs overpaid? Academy of
Management Perspectives, 22(2), 5–20.
Kedia, B. L., Mukherjee, D., & Lahiri, S. (2006). Indian
business groups: Evolution and transformation. Asia Pa-
cific Journal of Management, 23(4), 559–577.
Khanna, T., & Yafeh, Y. (2007). Business groups in emerg-
ing markets: Paragons or parasites? Journal of Economic
Literature, 45(2), 331–372.
Khoury, T. A., & Peng, M. W. (2008). Does institutional
reform of intellectual property rights lead to more FDI in
emerging economies? (Working paper). Richardson, TX:
University of Texas at Dallas.
Kostova, T., Roth, K., & Dacin, M. T. (2008). Institutional
theory in the study of multinational corporations: A
critique and new directions. Academy of Management
Review, 33(4), 994–1006.
Kotha, S., Dunbar, R., & Bird, A. (1995). Strategic action
generation: A comparison of emphasis placed on generic
competitive methods by U.S. and Japanese managers.
Strategic Management Journal, 16(3), 195–220.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2008).
The economic consequences of legal origins. Journal of
Economic Literature, 46(2), 285–332.
Lau, C. M., & Bruton, G. D. (2008). FDI in China: What
we know and what we need to study next. Academy of
Management Perspectives, 22(4), 30–44.
Lawrence, P., & Lorsch, J. (1969). Organization and environ-
ment. Homewood, IL: Irwin.
Lee, K. B., Peng, M. W., & Lee, K. (2008). From diversifi-
cation premium to diversification discount during insti-
tutional transitions. Journal of World Business, 43(1),
47–65.
Lee, S.-H., & Oh, K. (2007). Corruption in Asia: Perva-
siveness and arbitrariness. Asia Pacific Journal of Manage-
ment, 24(1), 97–114.
Lee, S.-H., Peng, M. W., & Barney, J. B. (2007). Bankruptcy
law and entrepreneurship development: A real options
perspective. Academy of Management Review, 32(1),
257–272.
Lewin, A., & Volberda, H. W. (1999). Prolegomena on
coevolution: A framework for research on strategy and
new organizational forms. Organization Science, 10(5),
519–534.
Li, J. J., Poppo, L., & Zhou, K. Z. (2008). Do managerial ties
in China always produce value? Competition, uncer-
tainty, and domestic vs. foreign firms. Strategic Manage-
ment Journal, 29(4), 383–400.
Li, Y., & Peng, M. W. (2008). Developing theory from
strategic management research in China. Asia Pacific
Journal of Management, 25(3), 563–572.
Liebowitz, S. J., & Margolis, S. (1999). Winners, losers, and
Microsoft. Oakland, CA: Independent Institute.
Lin, Z., Peng, M. W., Yang, H., & Sun, S. L. (2009). How
do networks and learning drive M&As? An institutional
comparison between China and the United States. Stra-
tegic Management Journal (in press).
Lu, J. W., & Beamish, P. W. (2004). International diversi-
fication and firm performance: The S-curve hypothesis.
Academy of Management Journal, 47, 598–609.
Lu, Y., Tsang, E., & Peng, M. W. (2008). Knowledge man-
agement and innovation strategy in the Asia Pacific:
Toward an institution-based view. Asia Pacific Journal of
Management, 25(3), 361–374.
Luo, Y., & Peng, M. W. (1999). Learning to compete in a
transition economy: Experience, environment, and per-
formance. Journal of International Business Studies, 30(2),
269–296.
Lyles, M., & Salk, J. (1996). Knowledge acquisition from
foreign partners in international joint ventures. Journal
of International Business Studies, 27(5), 877–904.
Mahlich, J. (2009). Patents and performance in the Japanese
pharmaceutical industry: An institution-based view. Asia
Pacific Journal of Management, 26 (in press, DOI 10.1007/
s10490-008-9128-x).
Makino, S., Isobe, T., & Chan, C. (2004). Does country
matter? Strategic Management Journal, 25(10), 1027–
1043.
Matsusaka, J. (1993). Takeover motives during the con-
glomerate merger wave. RAND Journal of Economics,
24(3), 357–379.
McGuire, J., & Dow, S. (2009). Japanese keiretsu: Past,
present, future. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 26(2),
333–352.
McKinley, W., Mone, M., & Moon, C. (1999). Determi-
nants and developments of schools in organization the-
ory. Academy of Management Review, 24, 634–648.
McMillan, J. (2007). Market institutions. In L. Blume & S.
Durlauf (Eds.), The new Palgrave dictionary of economics
(2nd ed.). London: Palgrave.
Meyer, J. W., & Rowan, B. (1977). Institutionalized
organizations: Formal structure as myth and ceremony.
American Journal of Sociology, 83(2), 340–363.
Meyer, K. E., Estrin, S., Bhaumik, S., & Peng, M. W.
(2009). Institutions, resources, and entry strategies in
emerging economies. Strategic Management Journal,
30(1), 61–80.
Narayanan, V. K., & Fahey, L. (2005). The relevance of the
institutional underpinnings of Porter's five forces frame-
work to emerging economies: An epistemological anal-
ysis. Journal of Management Studies, 42(1), 207–223.
New York Times (2009, January 29). Obama calls Wall
Street bonuses shameful. Retrieved February 2, 2009,
from http://www.nytimes.com/2009/01/30/business/
30obama.html?partner⫽rss&emc⫽rss.
North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change, and
2009 79Peng, Sun, Pinkham, and Chen
economic performance. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univer-
sity Press.
North, D. C. (2005). Understanding the process of economic
change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
North, D. C. (2009). The Chinese menu (for development).
In M. W. Peng (Ed.), Global business (pp. 110–111).
Cincinnati, OH: South-Western Cengage Learning.
North, D. C., Wallis, J., & Weingast, B. R. (2006). A
conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human his-
tory. (Working paper 12795). Cambridge, MA: National
Bureau of Economic Research.
Oliver, C. (1997). Sustainable competitive advantage:
Combining institutional and resource-based views. Stra-
tegic Management Journal, 18(9), 679–713.
Oliver, C., & Holzinger, I. (2008). The effectiveness of
strategic political management: A dynamic capabilities
framework. Academy of Management Review, 33(2), 496 –
520.
Peng, M. W. (2002). Towards an institution-based view of
business strategy. Asia Pacific Journal of Management,
19(2/3), 251–267.
Peng, M. W. (2003). Institutional transitions and strategic
choices. Academy of Management Review, 28(2), 275–
296.
Peng, M. W. (2004). Identifying the big question in inter-
national business research. Journal of International Busi-
ness Studies, 35(2), 99–108.
Peng, M. W. (2006). Global strategy. Cincinnati, OH:
South-Western Thomson.
Peng, M. W. (2009). Global strategy (2nd ed.). Cincinnati,
OH: South-Western Cengage Learning.
Peng, M. W., & Chen, H. (2009). Strategic responses to
global institutional pressures in the Chinese toy industry.
International Studies of Management and Organization (in
press).
Peng, M. W., & Delios, A. (2006). What determines the
scope of the firm over time and around the world? An
Asia Pacific perspective. Asia Pacific Journal of Manage-
ment, 23(4), 385–405.
Peng, M. W., & Heath, P. (1996). The growth of the firm in
planned economies in transition: Institutions, organiza-
tions, and strategic choices. Academy of Management
Review, 21(2), 492–528.
Peng, M. W., & Jiang, Y. (2009). Institutions behind family
ownership and control in large firms. Journal of Manage-
ment Studies (in press).
Peng, M. W., & Khoury, T. A. (2008). Unbundling the
institution-based view of international business strategy.
In A. Rugman (Ed.), Oxford handbook of international
business (pp. 256 –268). Oxford, UK: Oxford University
Press.
Peng, M. W., Lee, S.-H., & Wang, D. (2005). What deter-
mines the scope of the firm over time? A focus on
institutional relatedness. Academy of Management Re-
view, 30(3), 622–633.
Peng, M. W., & Luo, Y. (2000). Managerial ties and firm
performance in a transition economy: The nature of a
micro-macro link. Academy of Management Journal,
43(3), 486–501.
Peng, M. W., & Pleggenkuhle-Miles, E. G. (2009). Current
debates in global strategy. International Journal of Man-
agement Reviews, 11(1), 51–68.
Peng, M. W., Wang, D., & Jiang, Y. (2008). An institution-
based view of international business strategy: A focus on
emerging economies. Journal of International Business
Studies, 39(5), 920–936.
Porter, M. E. (1980). Competitive strategy. New York: Free
Press.
Powell, W. W. (1996). Commentary on the nature of insti-
tutional embeddedness. Advances in Strategic Manage-
ment, 13, 293–300.
Priem, R. L., & Butler, J. E. (2001). Is the resource-based
"view" a useful perspective for strategic management
research? Academy of Management Review, 26(1), 22–40.
Puffer, S. M., & McCarthy, D. J. (2007). Can Russia's
state-managed, network capitalism be competitive? In-
stitutional pull versus institutional push. Journal of World
Business, 42(1), 1–13.
Ren, B., Au, K., & Birtch, T. A. (2009). China's business
network structure during institutional transitions. Asia
Pacific Journal of Management, 26(2), 219–240.
Rugman, A. (2005). The regional multinationals. Cambridge,
UK: Cambridge University Press.
Rumelt, R., Schendel, D., & Teece, D. (Eds.) (1994). Fun-
damental issues in strategy: A research agenda. Boston:
Harvard Business School Press.
Schmalensee, R. (2000). Antitrust issues in Schumpeterian
industries. American Economic Review, 90(2), 192–196.
Schuler, D., Rehbein, K., & Cramer, R. (2002). Pursuing
strategic advantage through political means. Academy of
Management Journal, 45(4), 659–672.
Scott, W. R. (1987). The adolescence of institutional the-
ory. Administrative Science Quarterly, 32(4), 493–511.
Scott, W. R. (1995). Institutions and organizations. Thousand
Oaks, CA: Sage.
Scott, W. R. (2008a). Approaching adulthood: The matur-
ing of institutional theory. Theory and Society, 37, 427–
442.
Scott, W. R. (2008b). Institutions and organizations: Ideas and
interests (3rd ed.). Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R.W. (1991). Takeovers in the '60s
and the '80s: Evidence and implications. Strategic Man-
agement Journal, 12(s2), 51–59.
Simon, H. A. (1961). Administrative behavior (2nd ed.). New
York: Macmillan.
Singh, K. (2007). The limited relevance of culture to strat-
egy. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 24(4), 421– 428.
Somaya, D., Williamson, I. O., & Zhang, X. (2007). Com-
bining patent law expertise with R&D for patenting
performance. Organization Science, 18(6), 922–937.
Stevenson, C. (2009). Bookoff, Amazon, and the Japanese
retail bookselling industry. In M. W. Peng (Ed.), Global
strategy (2nd ed., pp. 387–395). Cincinnati, OH: South-
Western Cengage Learning.
Tong, T., Reuer, J., & Peng, M. W. (2008). International
joint ventures and the value of growth options. Academy
of Management Journal, 51(5), 1014–1029.
Walker, G., Madson, T. L., & Carini, G. (2002). How does
institutional change affect heterogeneity among firms?
Strategic Management Journal, 23(2), 89–102.
80 AugustAcademy of Management Perspectives
Wall Street Journal. (2008a, September 5). Dell plans to sell
factories in effort to cut costs.
Wall Street Journal. (2008b, October 22). Uncle Sam goes
car crazy?
Walsh, J. (2008). CEO compensation and the responsibili-
ties of the business scholar to society. Academy of Man-
agement Perspectives, 22(3), 26–33.
Wan, W. P., & Hoskisson, R. E. (2003). Home country
environments, corporate diversification strategies, and
firm performance. Academy of Management Journal,
46(1), 27–45.
Webb, J. W., Tihanyi, L., Ireland, R. D., & Sirmon, D. G.
(2009). You say illegal, I say legitimate: Entrepreneur-
ship in the informal economy. Academy of Management
Review (in press).
Williamson, O. E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: Analysis
and antitrust implications. New York: Free Press.
Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of capi-
talism. New York: Free Press.
Wright, M., Filatotchev, I., Hoskisson, R. E., & Peng, M. W.
(2005). Strategy research in emerging economies: Chal-
lenging the conventional wisdom. Journal of Management
Studies, 42(1), 1–33.
Xu, D., & Shenkar, O. (2002). Institutional distance and
the multinational enterprise. Academy of Management
Review, 27(4), 608–618.
Yamakawa, Y., Peng, M. W., & Deeds, D. (2008). What
drives new ventures to internationalize from emerging to
developed economies? Entrepreneurship Theory and Prac-
tice, 32(1), 59–82.
Yang, X., Jiang, Y., Kang, R., & Ke, Y. (2009). A compar-
ative analysis of the internationalization of Chinese and
Japanese firms. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 26(1),
141–162.
Yoshikawa, T., & McGuire, J. (2008). Change and conti-
nuity in Japanese corporate governance. Asia Pacific Jour-
nal of Management, 25(1), 5–24.
Young, M., Peng, M. W., Ahlstrom, D., Bruton, G., & Jiang,
Y. (2008). Governing the corporation in emerging
economies: A review of the principal-principal perspec-
tive. Journal of Management Studies, 45(1), 196–220.
Zacharakis, A. L., McMullen, J. S., & Shepherd, D. A.
(2007). Venture capitalists' decision policies across three
countries: An institutional theory perspective. Journal of
International Business Studies, 38(5), 691–708.
Zhou, K. Z., Poppo, L., & Yang, Z. (2008). Relational ties or
customized contracts? An examination of alternative
governance choices in China. Journal of International
Business Studies, 39(3), 526–534.
2009 81Peng, Sun, Pinkham, and Chen
... Formal institutions have a direct impact on the behaviour of firms and managers as they directly prohibit specific activities or alter their outcomes (Scott, 1995(Scott, , 2008. Accordingly, extensive research on the interplay between resources and formal institutions provides evidence that formal institutions affect the value of managerial resources (Peng, Sun, Pinkham & Chen, 2009). Hence, we expect formal gender-related institutions to alter the value of resources of female managers. ...
- Felix Hoch
Research investigating the relationship between firm performance and gender diversity has so far reported conflicting evidence: Some studies find firm performance to benefit from gender diversity, others find negative results or no effect at all. Taking this inconclusive evidence as a sign for moderators influencing the effect of gender diversity on firm performance, we investigate the moderating influence of institutions on this relationship. Using data on 7,661 firms in 71 countries, we employ a multilevel linear regression with fixed effects to examine the moderating effect of formal as well as informal institutional characteristics. We find that institutions indeed moderate the relationship between gender diversity and firm performance. In particular, informal institutions seem to moderate the effect of diversity on market valuation (Tobin's Q), while formal institutions moderate the effect of gender diversity on firm financial performance (ROA). These results have important theoretical implications for the academic debate on gender diversity and firm performance as well as practical implications for both businesses and lawmakers.
... The strategy tripod perspective suggests that the firm (resource) and the market (industry) based views of the firm alone, while powerful, are not sufficient to explain the complexity of entrepreneurship. Instead, the combination of the three legs of the strategy tripod (firm, markets and institutions) provide a better understanding of firm strategies (Peng et al., 2009;Yamakawa, Peng, & Deeds, 2008). The rise of the institution-based view as an influential theoretical tool is an outcome of Kiggundu, Jørgensen, and Hafsi's (1983) call for new theoretical tools to capture the complex and rapid change in the organizationenvironment relationships in emerging economies. ...
The chapter explores the change in educational philosophies application through the rapid adaptation of simulations and technologies
... Companies' legitimacy processes and social behaviours depend heavily on the institutional environments' characteristics, which can force them to adopt shared rules and norms (Campbell, 2007), meaning, that beyond firm-specific characteristics, institutions can also influence corporate decision-making processes and strategy (Peng et al., 2009). Not all institutional environments have the same quality levels, and, under low quality conditions, informal institutions can often emerge, which make the relationship between legitimacy and legality more complex (Palmas et al., 2014;Webb et al., 2009Webb et al., , 2013. ...
As Legality Rating (LR) for Italian companies was only recently introduced, it is an under-investigated phenomenon that is difficult to univocally interpret or structure within a well-defined theoretical framework. Given that certain governance characteristics can drive strategic decisions and have a crucial role to play in the legitimacy process, this paper sets out to explore how governance can influence a firm's attitude and signal its socially responsible behaviour, in terms of legality. We investigated both corporate and regional governance antecedents using a sample of 1049 private Italian firms with a listed LR in 2016. We analysed hierarchical linear models with the LR score as a dependent variable, ranging from one to seven points. As a first in governance studies, we adopted the European Quality of Government Index to investigate differences in regional-level governance. We found that board size, ownership concentration, foreign ownership and being a cooperative were positively related to LR. Our results show that, where governance features make firms more inclined to safeguard their reputation, the LR is higher. Thus, rather than encouraging changes oriented to greater respect for the principles of legality, the LR primarily highlights companies that already behave honourably. Finally, a battery of robustness tests and further analyses on the role of regional governance quality reveal a substitution effect between regional and corporate governance.
... Peng et al. (2008) discuss formal; regulatory; and informal, normative and cultural dimensions. Organizations are legitimate when they respond and behave according to pressures exerted by external stakeholders and established institutions, which reduce uncertainty and define boundaries (Ketokivi and Schroeder, 2004;Peng et al., 2009). Thus, the institutional factors affecting organizational decision-making can be seen as either hindrances or enablers. ...
- Olena Klymenko
- Lise Lillebrygfjeld Halse
The purpose of this paper is to investigate how sustainable practices in supply chains are affected by the COVID-19 pandemic through the lens of institutional theory. The study suggests that during the COVID-19 pandemic, companies tend to focus on short-term decisions and economic issues. The long-term focus on sustainability has, however, increased at the cluster level. The research also indicates that the pandemic has led to the development of new business routines that may transform institutional norms. The diversity of institutional contexts can, on the one hand, drive sustainability transitions through pressures and supportive programs but, on the other hand, also hinder the development of sustainability thinking.
... It is well-acknowledged in the literature that the host country institutions influence a firm's strategy and performance (Buckley & Munjal, 2017;Chan, Isobe, & Makino, 2008;Peng, Sun, Pinkham, & Chen, 2009;Scott, 1995;Daude & Stein, 2007;Julio & Yook, 2016;Zhang et al., 2011). Existing studies have revealed the direct effect of host countries' institutional quality on CBA completion (Zhang et al., 2011(Zhang et al., , 2017. ...
- Zhang Jianhong
This paper contributes to the literature on emerging multinational enterprises (EMNEs) by revealing how the conditions in their home countries influence their cross-border acquisitions. The study focuses on the liability of emergingness (LOE). It develops an integrative theoretical framework based on neo-institutional theory and the concept of legitimacy to explain the relationship between LOE and EMNEs' cross-border acquisitions completion and the situational conditions that shape this relationship. The study uses data on 27,648 announced acquisitions conducted by EMNEs from 24 emerging economies in 175 host countries to estimate the relationships. The results reveal that, while two types of LOE (economic and institutional) have negative impacts on cross-border acquisition completion, the negative impacts become less important or disappear when the host country's unemployment rate is too high, and the host country's institutional quality is too low. This finding suggests that EMNEs can mitigate the negative effect of the LOE by carefully choosing a good time and a suitable location to enter into these transactions.
... Speculation about an "institutional void" helped popularize the argument, highlighting the untapped business opportunities that are up for grabs for those who apply strategies that "fit emerging markets" (Khanna et al., 2005). In the search for fitting strategies, Peng pushed early and consistently for institution-based strategy research (Peng, 2002(Peng, , 2003(Peng, , 2014Peng et al., 2009). In this framework, formal and informal institutions not only influence industry-based competition as well as firm specific resources and capabilities, but also directly determine the suitability of distinct strategies. ...
- Sonja Opper
Almost two decades ago, Asia Pacific Journal of Management , 19(2/3): 251–267 Peng (2002) called attention to the promise of institution-based strategy research. The puzzle was to explain differences in strategies around the globe. Building on the work accomplished so far, I ask: Can institution-based strategy succeed when embedded in inappropriate social networks? Institutions and networks are usually studied as separate phenomena, yet each also defines the capabilities of the other. Institutions shape social network contacts and structures because institutions define opportunities for affiliation and the relative value of distinct contacts and network structures. At the same time, social networks shape institutions and organizations' capabilities for institutional innovation. Thus, the social network in which a manager or organization is embedded can either amplify or counteract success in implementing institution-based strategy. After I review the co-constitutional nature of institutions and networks and discuss a number of sample studies using China as a productive research site, I sketch questions that need to be answered to more tightly integrate network behavior into institutional strategy research, and discuss four emerging areas of research into how network-strategy fit affects performance: (1) network fit to adaptive strategy, (2) network fit to change strategy, (3) institutional dynamics and network-strategy fit, and (4) institutional distance and network-strategy fit.
- Fábio Lotti Oliva
- Pedro Marins Freire Teberga
- Lucas Israel Oliveira Testi
- Miguel Pina Cunha
Startups in the Brazilian organizational scenario have been growing fast and understanding these startups' internationalization strategies have been highly relevant. Such startups have developed a social, environmental, and economic impact solution that had the support of government programs in its internationalization process, seeking to understand the impact of these programs. This article has sought the following: (1) identify the risks and critical success factors in the internationalization process of born global startups of industry 4.0, (2) analyze the social, environmental, and economic aspects. The authors have based the methodology on a single-case analysis, a global startup - Asel-Tech, a technology and automation company focused on developing and providing solutions for leak detection in oil pipelines and derivatives. Among the main results, we highlight: (1) the proposition of a model for risk and critical success factors analysis in the internationalization of born global startups of industry 4.0, (2) the analysis from the institutional view perspective on the strategy, on the social, environmental, and economic aspects of digital manufacturing. For professionals, the article provides a model to assist startups in future internationalization processes.
- Mehmet Bagis
Bu araştırma 1991-2021 arasında dinamik yeteneklerin entelektüel yapısını incelemeyi amaçlamaktadır. Araştırmanın verileri Web of Science veri tabanındaki veri süzme kriterleri çerçevesinde ulaşılan 7.792 çalışmadan oluşmaktadır. Veriler, VOSviewer yazılımıyla analiz edilmiş ve araştırmada bibliyometrik analiz tekniklerinden ortak kelime analizi kullanılmıştır. Bulgular 1991-2001 arasında dinamik yetenekler araştırmalarına kaynak temelli görüş, kaynaklar, yetenekler, rekabet avantajı ve inovasyon kavramlarının hâkim olduğunu göstermektedir. 2002-2011 arasında ise dinamik yetenekler, kaynak temelli görüş, rekabet avantajı, performans, bilgi temelli görüş, bilgi yönetimi, örgütsel öğrenme, stratejik ittifaklar, inovasyon ve özümseme kapasitesi gibi kavramlar hâkim duruma gelmiştir. Son olarak 2012-2021 arasında ise dinamik yetenekler, kaynak temelli görüş, bilgi yönetimi, örgütsel çift yeteneklilik, araştırmacı ve fırsatçı yenilikler, rekabet avantajı, açık inovasyon, özümseme kapasitesi, firma performansı, girişimcilik, girişimsel yönelim, iş modeli, iş modeli inovasyonu, örgütsel öğrenme, uluslararasılaşma, pazarlama yeteneği, ittifaklar, tedarik zinciri yönetimi, büyük veri, dijitalizasyon, dijital dönüşüm, örgütsel çeviklik ve esneklik, mikro temeller, liderlik ve yönetişim kavramları öne çıkmıştır. Bu bulgular temelinde çalışma, gelecek araştırma önerileriyle tamamlanmıştır.
Our research builds on existing literature examining institutional voids in emerging economies. Using data from two cases of mining FDI in Argentina, we conceptualize the triggers, processes and consequences of informal institution-building by a social movement. We found the cases to exhibit different 'community sustainability orientations', enabling two contrasting strategies, 'bargaining' and 'gatekeeping', to address the existing institutional void. This led to the development of new formal institutions – regulated CSR for the former and legal ban on mining operations for the latter case. Our study thus offers insights into the processes through which institutional entrepreneurship by social movements influences MNEs.
- M.W. Peng
- Theodore A. Khoury
Critics suggest that the industry-based view has the five forces framework and the resource-based view converges on the VRIO framework, yet what specific propositions or frameworks does the institution-based view of IB strategy have? This article addresses this important and legitimate question, by identifying and articulating the two core propositions underpinning the institution-based view: (1) individuals and firms act rationally according to formal and informal institutional structures; (2) when formal institutions fail, informal institutions regulate exchange relationships. In other words, this article endeavours to advance the institution-based view of IB strategy by unbundling the broad proposition that 'institutions matter'. It leverages and extends contemporary research to illustrate the explanatory and predictive power of the two propositions underpinning the institution-based view of IB strategy.
- Paula Jarzabkowski
Research on top managers' strategizing behavior has addressed how they shape either the structural context or the interpretations of organization members. I offer a struc-turation theory framework integrating these two partial explanations and treating strategy shaping as socially dynamic. A qualitative seven-year analysis of top managers in three universities shows a sequential pattern of shaping strategy first in the action and then in the institutional realm, and also a simultaneous pattern of shaping strategy in both realms at once. Both patterns are successful in weakly institutionalized strategy contexts, whereas the simultaneous pattern is more successful in strongly institutionalized strategy contexts.
- Michael C. Jensen
- William H. Meckling
This paper integrates elements from the theory of agency, the theory of property rights and the theory of finance to develop a theory of the ownership structure of the firm. We define the concept of agency costs, show its relationship to the 'separation and control' issue, investigate the nature of the agency costs generated by the existence of debt and outside equity, demonstrate who bears the costs and why, and investigate the Pareto optimality of their existence. We also provide a new definition of the firm, and show how our analysis of the factors influencing the creation and issuance of debt and equity claims is a special case of the supply side of the completeness of markets problem.
- Donald C. Hambrick
- Ming-Jer Chen
Numerous histories of the early days of individual academic fields have been written, but scholars generally have stopped short of proposing generalizable frameworks or testable propositions for why these focal fields survived and prospered. We integrate logics from social movement theory and the sociology of science to model the rise of an aspiring academic community as an admittance-seeking social movement consisting of three major elements: differentiation, mobilization, and legitimacy building. We offer propositions based on in-depth analysis of the rise of a specific field-strategic management-within the administrative sciences.
This paper examines the role of institutional analysis within the field of international business (IB) studies. Within IB, institutions matter, but the view of institutions tends to be "thin", utilizing summary indicators rather than detailed description, and thus approaches institutions as unidimensional ''variables" that impact on particular facets of business activity. This paper argues that IB research would be usefully advanced by greater attention to comparing the topography of institutional landscapes and understanding their diversity. A number of alternative case-based approaches are outlined that draw on a growing "comparative capitalisms" literature in sociology and political science. The paper develops a number of empirical examples to show the utility and limits of these approaches for IB scholars.
Posted by: granvillegranvillebaisone0270045.blogspot.com
Source: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/241354238_The_Institution-Based_View_as_a_Third_Leg_for_a_Strategy_Tripod
0 Comments